Économie, emploi

Cette page regroupe l'ensemble des publications de Futuribles sur cette thématique (Vigie, revue, bibliographie, études, etc.)

Bibliography

Économie, emploi - Géopolitique

Une autre mondialisation en mouvement ?

Qui sont les opposants à la mondialisation néolibérale ? Quand sont-ils apparus pour la première fois ? Quels sont leurs modes d'action ? Quels sont leurs thèmes de contestation ? Contre qui se battent-ils réellement ? C'est à toutes ces questions que tente de répondre Karen Bastien dans un dossier de synthèse situé en deuxième partie de l'ouvrage. Avant de retracer la genèse des « altermondialistes » (« Pour une autre mondialisation ») en France et à l'étranger, l'auteur prévient que ce mouvement de ...

(290 more words)

Bibliography

Économie, emploi

Rapport d’information sur les perspectives économiques à l’horizon 2007 et le pacte de stabilité et de croissance

Dans une première partie, le rapport étudie les perspectives de l'économie française et des finances publiques à l'horizon 2007. Il examine l'environnement économique européen de la France, les perspectives macroéconomiques à moyen terme et les hypothèses de croissance. Il estime que l'équilibre des finances publiques ne sera pas atteint à l'échéance 2007 et qu'il est important de bien gérer les dépenses publiques. Pour ce faire, il propose, dans une deuxième partie, de refonder la ...

(15 more words)

Bibliography

Économie, emploi

Géographie de la mondialisation

Alors que de nombreux chercheurs et essayistes ont tendance à privilégier les dimensions économiques, politiques et sociales de la mondialisation, Laurent Carroué rappelle avec justesse l'importance des réalités spatiales du phénomène. « La mondialisation repose d'abord et avant tout sur la mise en relation de différents ensembles géographiques », précise-t-il d'emblée dans son ouvrage. Selon le géographe et géopoliticien français, trop d'études négligent la dimension géographique de ce phénomène au cœur des relations internationales. Partant de la définition ...

(139 more words)

Bibliography

Économie, emploi - Géopolitique

L’Europe et la mondialisation

Cet ouvrage collectif rassemble les contributions de responsables politiques, d'universitaires et d'acteurs de terrain qui se sont penchés, à l'invitation de l'Institut des relations internationales et stratégiques (IRIS) lors d'un colloque organisé en février 2002, sur la question du rôle de l'Europe face à la mondialisation. Forts de leur expérience, de leur engagement et de leur réflexion, les auteurs ont tenté de répondre aux questions suivantes : l'Union européenne peut-elle être le vecteur d ...

(224 more words)

Revue

Économie, emploi - Population

Économie et migrations. Des déterminants et impacts économics des migrations internationales

What are the reasons underlying the flows of international migration and its social and economic consequences for both the sending and receiving countries? Although these questions are extremely important, they have unfortunately been little studied. The topic is widely seen as taboo and, in the absence of solid expert knowledge, tends to be addressed mainly from a purely ideological standpoint.
Stéphane Justeau does not claim to provide an answer to the problem, which needs to be approached from many different angles -demographic, cultural, social and political. But as an economist, he offers some valuable insights into what makes individuals decide to emigrate and onto the impact these migrations have on employment and earnings levels in the receiving countries.
Basically, he shows the part played, among other things, by wage differentials in the behaviour of migrants. He then stresses the tiny impact of immigration on the earnings and employment of existing residents. He thus provides some useful pointers towards a more detailed and thorough analysis of a phenomenon that still needs a great deal more investigation.

Bibliography

Économie, emploi - Population

2000-2040 : population active et croissance

Le vieillissement de la population française va avoir des conséquences sur l'économie et en particulier sur l'évolution de la population active. Un des moyens de combler le déficit de main d'oeuvre serait une remontée des taux d'activité, notamment aux âges extrêmes de la vie active. La suppression progressive des dispositifs de cessation d'activité permettrait une hausse du taux d'activité des plus âgés, et le cumul emploi-formation une augmentation de celui des plus jeunes.

Forum

Économie, emploi - Société, modes de vie

La « disneylandisation » de la société

This piece is more polemical in style than those usually published by Futuribles. But it reflects a major trend that, whatever one feels about it, is striking and undoubtedly deserves our attention.
The trend Bernard Vaudour-Faguet criticizes is the "disneyfication" of society, by which the author also means the "leisure boom" and the proliferation of popular events and entertainments, which he describes and tries to analyse.
In addition to his observations, the author does not hide the fact that he thinks this phenomenon is "the wrong solution to the malaise" of our societies, that it arises from a serious breakdown of values and is a worrying symptom of the "decline of our civilization".
This judgement may be harsh, but nonetheless the phenomenon needs to be highlighted and its motives and consequences should be investigated further.

Revue

Économie, emploi - Éducation

La place de l’École dans l’économie en France

Using the metaphor of painting, Jean-Michel Saussois sets out to provide here three broad-brush pictures representing the rôle of schools in the economy and society in France, the first two looking back to the thirty Glorious Years (the "Trente Glorieuses") followed by the thirty Lean Years, while the third looks forward to the developments linked to what is commonly called "the knowledge-based economy".
Against this historical backdrop, he analyses the dynamic interaction between the tasks given to schools and the changes in priorities and means of regulating the economy and society. Thus between the end of World War II and the end of the 1960s, the French republican élitist model fitted well with the Fordist organization of industrial production. During the subsequent 30 years, characterized by increasing globalization and a growing reliance on market forces, new forms of competition destabilized both the Fordist compromise and the crucial role of schools in facilitating upward social mobility, as well as the tight links between diplomas, skills and remuneration. Although paper qualifications have become more essential than ever, they are now less and less a guarantee of upward social mobility. The result has been a loss of confidence in schools, while even more is expected of them. The current rise of the knowledge-based economy demands new skills, some of which can be acquired and assessed only on the job, and this leads to the emergence of new markets in skills that oblige schools to redefine their key role and to change their ways of operating.

Revue

Économie, emploi

Le cycle Kondratieff : mythe et réalité

The upturn in economic growth in France since 1997, a few years later than in the United States, has been interpreted in a number of different ways. For many observers, it suggests the start of a new phase of expansion, following logically, as required by the Kondratiev cycles, on the "Thirty Lean Years" that succeeded the post-war period of growth.
According to many enthusiastic believers in the Kondratiev function, our economies are subject to phases of expansion and then of less rapid growth occurring inevitably, no matter what we do, every 50 years; the present upturn is supposedly stimulated by a favourable international environment and the coming-of-age of the information and communications technologies.
Éric Bosserelle argues that this is a crass and wrongheaded interpretation of the theories of Nicolaï Kondratiev, who was interested only in long-term fluctuations in prices and never claimed to construct a theory that would be able to explain the past, let alone predict future patterns of economic growth.
Bosserelle reminds us of some essential truths about Kondratiev's work, the somewhat fragile empirical basis for it and the long-term fluctuations that he brought to light. He demonstrates the advantages as well as the limits of the theories, including those that arose from the particular circumstances of the period Kondratiev studied.
He therefore stresses that the Kondratiev cycles are concerned with the dynamics of prices of basic products over the long term, a concern that is unfortunately completely or partially overlooked by modern theories, none of which has managed to deal convincingly with a key question: the recurrence of cycles lasting half a century. Consequently, Éric Bosserelle concludes, it would be as well to remain cautious with regard to certain fashionable viewpoints which suggest that our economies are going to develop according to unalterable laws.

Bibliography

Économie, emploi

« L’Afrique en chantier »

Face à un constat qui ne peut qu'être pessimiste (depuis 40 ans - date de l'accession à l'indépendance - la plupart des pays africains n'a pas connu d'élévation de leur niveau de vie ni d'amélioration de la situation des droits de l'homme, au contraire), ce nouveau numéro de la revue de la Société de Stratégie réunit des auteurs, personnalités africaines politiques comme Abdoulaye Wade, Président du Sénégal, chef d'entreprise (Paul K. Fokam) ou avocat ...

(260 more words)

Revue

Économie, emploi - Territoires, réseaux

À quoi bon l’économie ? De l’économie à la politique : l’exemple des transports

Economics is the only discipline, among the social sciences at least, which tries to be both descriptive and normative. In fact, however, as it is often difficult to find corroboration from empirical observations, economics tends to fall back on a theoretical approach; economic recommendations are rarely robust or consensual, and ultimately have little impact on decision-making.
To counter such criticisms, Quinet and Walliser focus on the field of transport, which is a special area of study within economics. They discuss three examples:
- transport of goods, which has been relatively well studied by economists, but their recommendations have tended to be blocked by vested interests, clinging to the status quo, even though the existing situation may be contrary to the collective interest as well as to their own interests in the long term;
- management of urban transport infrastructures, where -once again- "expert" opinion comes up against the inertia of institutions that fight to retain their position and defend their privileges;
- control of urban traffic flows, a particularly delicate matter, where opinions are divided and recommendations, once again, are thwarted by the lack of a common stance, with everyone concerned acting in accordance with their own particular logic.
As transport economists, are Émile Quinet and Bernard Walliser simply disappointed that their advice is not followed? No, they start by taking a critical look at their own field. "The models cannot cope with the diversity of the real world: every situation is unusual, there is no such thing as an average user, a representative firm or a standard cost." The measures proposed are "too blind and clumsy, and fail to reach their targets". Transport economists do not, above all, take sufficient account of the way the actors operate.
The authors conclude with some suggestions for ways in which economics might make progress. But they harbour no illusions: economists recommend change. For this to occur, their recommendations must chime with what the decision-makers want, something that the economists cannot determine...

Revue

Économie, emploi - Recherche, sciences, techniques

Nouvelles technologies et emploi. À propos d’une étude du BIPE sur l’impact des technologies de l’information et de la communication

Anne de Beer and Gérard Blanc comment here on a recent study by the BIPE on the impact of the information and communications technologies (ICTs) on growth, productivity and employment.
We know that over two decades the investments in ICTs seem not to have had a major impact on productivity and employment -hence Solow's famous paradox: "computers are everywhere except in the statistics". Perhaps, suggest the authors, this is because the introduction of these technologies required a considerable effort of organizational and sociocultural adaptation and innovation which occurred slowly.
According to the BIPE, however, the impact of the ICTs appears to have been clearly positive, first in the United States since the mid 1990s, slightly later in France. Not only did these technologies constitute an extremely dynamic sector but, in addition, they encouraged the whole range of economic activities and therefore had a major multiplier effect on growth, productivity and employment.
Basing its study on the structure of the French economy in 1998, the BIPE attempted to estimate the multiplier effect that the ICTs might have on the French economy between now and 2003. This article briefly reviews these simulations, which are quite promising.

Bibliography

Économie, emploi

« Les banques : quel rôle, quel risque, quel avenir ? »

La banque apparaît aujourd'hui dans une situation contradictoire : d'un côté elle témoigne du pouvoir de la finance, comme le montrent les méga-fusions des dernières années, de l'autre, son activité est devenue de plus en plus « contestable » (au sens de la théorie des marché contestables de W. Baumol). La déréglementation et la désintermédiation, ainsi que l'apparition de la concurrence en ligne modifient profondément le métier de la banque. Malgré cette mutation, la banque préserve une place privilégiée ...

(56 more words)

Bibliography

Économie, emploi

« Quel avenir pour les places financières ? »

Les places financières ne restent pas étrangères à la mondialisation économique. En effet, les dernières années témoignent d'un large mouvement de concentration des Bourses internationales. Va-t-on alors vers une place mondiale unique ? Avant de répondre à cette question, Frédéric Lelièvre montre d'abord que les principales places financières sont aujourd'hui devenues des entreprises comme les autres. Elles vendent néanmoins un bien particulier, l'accès à un marché, ce qui crée des conflits d'intérêt. Dans le même temps ...

(35 more words)

Revue

Économie, emploi - Recherche, sciences, techniques

Réflexions sur la nouvelle économie

With the Internet and the spread of the information and communication technologies (ITCs), one noticed the emergence (especially in the United States of America) of the concept of a "Net-economy", as well as the one, broader, of a "new economy". Their advocates argue that we would have entered a new era, characterized by a technological and economic paradigm that would be totally different from the former.
Frédéric Teulon first indicates what this concept of a "new economy" means, and explains how the idea could emerge that the growth of the ITCs -as well as those of the rail in the XIXth century and of the electricity and the car in the XXth - can signify a new era. The author wonders how it could denote that we would be now at the beginning of a new upswing in the Kondratieff cycle. In this regard, he points out the effective improvements accomplished, despite the delay justifying Solow's paradox -computers can be seen everywhere except in the productivity rate- and due to the deep restructuring of the American productive system.
But, even if technological innovation is patent and if information now represents the main factor of wealth, it does not necessarily mean that the past economic rules are outdated. Frédéric Teulon, through various examples, demonstrates that on the contrary these remain really relevant: the ITCs do not imply the end of the big firm, of the market economy (vs. economy of the free), of integration, of the risk of inflation...
It is important not to be deluded by the takeoff of the Nasdaq -Nasdaq which has lost half its value since March 2000... Many start-ups will be bankrupt... All this is normal: the "new economy" functions in the same way as the old; if technical improvement permitted growth, the fact remains that the problematic of development is much more complex than what is explained by those who want to present a univocal answer. Economic, fiscal and monetary policies, for instance, remain as far important.

Revue

Économie, emploi - Éducation - Société, modes de vie

Savoirs libérateurs et savoirs oppressifs

Everyone agrees that poverty is dreadful and that its eradication should be a top priority. Yet while knowledge is recognized to be the greatest form of wealth for today's societies, enormous inequalities are developing not just in financial terms but also in access to knowledge.
Xavier Godinot sets out here to show that there are different sorts of knowledge: theoretical knowledge, which is often the most highly valued -and is indeed the basis for a process of segregation- but also knowledge related to living and acting, not to mention spiritual knowledge, which is probably shared more equitably but which is harder to express, recognize and turn to good account.
The fight against poverty cannot be limited to efforts that allow a few to escape from want while others are relegated to the categories of disabled and unemployable. Nor cannot it succeed by relying on pseudo-training courses in which noble "manipulators of symbols" claim to instruct the poor, or by maintaining a two-tier system of training and job placement that merely reinforces inequalities, especially given that the educational system cannot on its own remedy the differences in family background.
Echoing the philosopher Michel Serres, Godinot stresses that "the fight against poverty and social exclusion does indeed involve the acquisition of knowledge [...] but it is above all about recognizing kinds of knowledge that are not valued", especially the kinds of knowledge related to living and acting that poor people have, and which need to be linked with theoretical types of knowledge.
Using as an example the experience gained in the "Quart Monde Université" programme, Godinot shows how it is possible, by bringing together poor people, social workers and academics against a background of mutual respect, for everyone to learn from everyone else and for the whole group to make progress - progress towards greater understanding of the processes whereby people become poor and excluded; progress towards the process of empowering the least fortunate in society.
Xavier Godinot is thus not content with denouncing poverty; he describes here a promising way forward based not on aid but on partnership, a partnership that ultimately enriches everyone involved, from the richest to the poorest.

Revue

Économie, emploi

Environnement et commerce international. Le principe de précaution sur la ligne de fracture

"The classical theory of free trade is based on the idea that free trade combined with competition will increase the welfare of all parties in the exchange." In short, that trade is a positive sum game and therefore any barriers to international trade can only harm overall welfare.
Olivier Godard argues here that this theory breaks down with regard to the environment. It assumes that all the elements in the cost of producing goods -in particular their adverse effects on the environment- are internalized by the producers. But in practice this is not true. Godard offers suggestions of what improvements therefore need to be made.
He starts by examining how to reconcile -by making some corrective adjustments- free trade and protection of the environment, in line with the source of the externalities (consumption patterns or methods of production) and their nature (local or global). But he then argues that the resulting typology is of limited value and cannot cope with the appearance of health and environmental risks that have not been verified scientifically, so that what matters in practice is the principle of risk aversion and how it is applied.
Some people may not find the arguments easy reading. But they undoubtedly address a key issue: how to adapt -perhaps change- the rules of free trade to take account of the new requirements related to protecting the environment or, to put it another way, how to restore a concern with the long term to the rules of international trade, to ensure both that they are respected and yet not wrongly exploited for protectionist reasons.
The article is not just about the national and international public bodies -the World Trade Organization in particular- but also about businesses facing the problems of where to locate their activities and how to remain competitive in world markets.

Forum

Économie, emploi - Institutions

Ecce homo… oeconomicus ou sapiens ? De l’avenir de la science économique

Taking as his starting-point a recent article by Richard Thaler on the future of economics, Alain Michel launches a vigorous attack on "economic science" which is interested only in homo oeconomicus with his supposedly rational behaviour, and pleads instead for "political economy" which is concerned with homo sapiens as a being also motivated by emotions, sensitivity, perhaps with a soul.
He shows how economists, utterly convinced of the scientific nature of their work, have managed to create a form of economics that is heavily mathematical and nothing to do with the real world -an approach that is admittedly not without interest, but its claims to objectivity are exaggerated and it lacks real descriptive force.
He points out that human beings are not bloodless agents who act in a purely rational way, so that their actions cannot be understood without combining the branches of knowledge that have been artificially separated in the name of science. He is therefore highly critical of the current scientism, and in fact highlights its limits; instead he argues passionately in favour of a more interdisciplinary approach that is better suited to an understanding of homo sapiens, who for that matter is a more congenial being.

Revue

Économie, emploi

France : retour au plein emploi ?

Edmond Malinvaud offers us here a masterly economics lecture on the subject of employment. It is in three parts: the first concentrates on the lessons of the past, the second looks at the prospects and issues between now and 2010, and the third examines the priorities that should govern French economic policy.
First of all he surveys the developments observed in the course of recent decades, stressing in particular the increasing levels of unemployment up to 1996, which he blames not so much on the frequently cited rigidities of French society as on rapid wage increases which were halted belatedly by a strong economic policy.
Then, observing that the French economy managed to generate 1.6 million jobs in the last four years as a result of a more favourable economic climate and an interventionist public policy, Malinvaud reflects on the prospects for economic growth, including those caused by the boom in new technologies and, above all, on the future increases in productivity -the factors boosting and holding it back- and the likelihood of a new situation of full employment, including the possible level of structural unemployment.
Along the way he stresses the risks of inflation and argues the need both for a "carefully judged macroeconomic policy" and for a reform of the welfare state so as to avoid, in particular, the traps of unemployment and low activity rates.
In the end, Edmond Malinvaud highlights the priorities that French economic policy ought to adopt if it is to achieve a better balance henceforth between economic and social concerns, and between efficiency and fairness.

Editorial

Économie, emploi - Institutions

Le mythe du plein emploi

Nous voici, en ce début de l'année 2001, à nouveau confrontés en France à deux enjeux qui, paradoxalement, demeurent traités de manière distincte : celui des perspectives d'emploi et celui de l'avenir des retraites.